Bounty: Staking Claims on Field of Knowledge
The realm of the possible physical laws is part of nature, too.
June 27, 2018
Jeffery J. Smith
Activist
“Despite being fact-filled, this article is more than 99.99% empty space.”

No Trespassing on Fields of Knowledge

Humans of our era understand that matter is an expression of energy, energy is an expression of subatomic particles, and subatomic particles are an expression of natural laws. Our era is coming to understand, but is not quite there yet, that matter, energy, and the laws of physics are all part of nature. The realm of logical solutions is as much a part of nature as is planet Earth. All of it exists without the input of any human’s labor or capital. And the best parts—the best locations—are extremely valuable.

Cities can expand, but there’s only one downtown location at Broadway and Main. Knowledge expands but there’s only one algorithm for the fastest web search. Whoever gets to own—directly or indirectly—the best locations and the most useful knowledge gets to rake in the most money.

Part of that income is earned, the part that is due to the owner applying their labor and capital. Part of that income is unearned, the part that is due to the owner excluding others from the best that nature has to offer. That second part—due to excluding everyone else—we call “rent” and with environmental “rent” and utilities “rent” belongs to the growing total of the worth of Earth in America.

Discovery

Before anyone discovered North America thousands of years ago—whether coming from Siberia or Scandinavia—it existed. Before any one or any crew of explorers discovered waves of gravity, they existed. And before anyone worked out the functions of trigonometry, they also existed as logical patterns, as rules in the only form that they could exist. Long before humans were able to discover them, such useful parts of nature were already available. Each discovery underpinned the next.

Just as long voyages to explore virgin territory depended on already occupying a home base and employing logic, so did learning the ways of the natural world depend on a pre-existing base of knowledge and following reason. As Sir Isaac Newton said, “If I have seen further than others it is because I have stood on the shoulders of giants.” Those shoulders belonged to thinkers like Copernicus and Bruno (who was burned at the stake). Later, if James Clerk Maxwell had not died young, he may have discovered e=mc^2 before Einstein but at least he paved the way for Albert.

Some discoveries don’t pay off. Indians were first to populate the Americas but did not make much off real estate speculation. Teams of scientists collaborated to discover gravity waves but none became rich in the process. And neither Newton nor Gottfried Wilhelm Leibnitz marketed calculus—which they outlined at nearly the same time. Only those who came after profited from such discoveries, usually due to excluding others.

Although two people can not occupy the same land at the same time, two people can utilize the same equation at the same time. My acquiring knowledge does not mean you have any less knowledge. Yet discoverers of logical solutions deserve reward. Do we moderns owe the descendants of Newton and Leibniz untold fortunes? Similar to how much we pay today’s authors of code, such as the Google guys?

Ownership of originality is huge in the modern world of constant progress and incessant litigation. For its part, technology has made major strides rapidly. The rather mundane doorknob actually is a rather recent invention, patented in 1878 (a year before land reformer Henry George’s classic, Progress and Poverty).

How far do the benefits of being first extend? Could the first crew of canoeists landing on what’s now Alaska claim all North and South America? Could the crew member who was first to set foot on the beach be the one to be entitled to the Western Hemisphere? And for how long? Forever? By now, with every inhabitable corner of the planet already inhabited, nobody can claim to be first. Nobody can even claim to descend from whoever arrived first, since tribes have always wandered all over the face of the earth.

Our privatizing of nature has been with us a while. Millennia ago, the Phoenicians gave their captains the order to sink their ship before allowing a pirate or foreign nation to capture it and discover the secret that allowed Phoenicians to sail from one end of the Mediterranean to the other—only the Punic sailors knew how to caulk their ships with tar. Millennia later, other Arabs kept secret the formula for steel which made their scimitars so much more deadly than heavy iron swords.

What if two people discovered an aspect of nature at the same time? The history of science is filled with smart guys breaking through at almost identical times. Nearly simultaneously:

It’s like something was in the air, that a few antenna could pick up. Should these pairs split the benefits 50/50?

Dibs

Being first confers the right to keep the discovery and exclude others from it. Even children know to be first to call “shotgun” so their siblings could not ride in the front passenger seat. “First come, first served.”

Even if you’re not first, you can still exclude others from land or the realm of logical solutions. Centuries ago big landowners, backed by the power of the state, got bigger by enclosing common land, preventing commoners from using it. Only the big owners could farm or graze sheep on land that once was available to all.

In our era, the AMA prevents a doctor from France—where the lifespan is longer than in America—from practicing medicine in America. That way, they decrease competition, swell their market share, overcharge their customers, and rake in more money. That’s a surplus which economists call “rent”.

This rent differs from that of utilities. The doctors’ monopoly is not natural but artificial. While it would be impractical to have parallel sewers compete, it’d not be impractical to let all doctors compete. On the contrary, it’d quite efficient to have more doctors competing among themselves.

While most of us make money by doing something useful, like being a doctor, a few get paid by preventing others from doing something useful, which is anti-social.

Owning aspects of nature differs from owning things that we do create. When you keep others from using your house or car or computer, there are plenty of other houses or cars or computers they can turn to, since people make them. But when you speculate in land, and your vacant lot keeps others from using a prime location downtown, then you hobble your local economy. Similarly, when you keep your idea to yourself and prevent others from building on it, then you hobble scientific progress.

Paper Claim

The authors of the US Constitution included patents and copyrights. People accept the notion that patents and copyrights protect the little guy—the basement inventor, the unheralded author. Yet it’s a star system; only a very few inventors and authors make any money from their patent, or composers from their copyright.

As Americans spread from the East Coast across the continent, they won from the federal government land patents. Just like the more familiar idea patents, those pieces of paper granted the patent holder a monopoly, over a sector of land rather a section of harmonious possibility. Getting a patent or copyright is like planting a flag on the field of orderly solutions. It prevents late-comers and anyone else from exploring that particular part of the natural world and deducing a similar correct answer.

The one to win a patent for the telephone, Alexander Graham Bell, walked out the door of the Patent Office as another inventor of the telephone (Elisha Gray) walked in. Should the guy a few minutes late win nothing and the guy a few minutes early win everything? What if the person who discovered or invented first was not the one who patented or copyrighted first? Snooze, you lose? Everything forever?

Patents and copyrights are getting longer. Bowing to investors, US politicians extended patents from 17 years to 20. That’s just the reverse of the adage, “the penalty does not fit the crime.” Here, the reward does not fit the creativity.

A more mature logic than shouting “dibs” in order to be first is taking turns—as harried parents try to teach their brood. For brainiacs and artists to take turns exploring the realm of logical possibility, patents and copyrights would have to expire much more quickly than now, after a couple years, not decades.

Go Into Business

Some patents don’t pay off. The discoverer can get one but never make a penny. Usually the gizmo is not marketable, but sometimes the discoverer gets ripped off. Almost all inventors and artists are too poor and desperate to have the leverage to negotiate a fair contract. Hence there are innumerable cases where, e.g., recording artists make peanuts while record companies keep hundreds of millions from the sales, and of people like the inventor of the windshield wiper fighting Ford his entire working career to win the profit he was owed (he eventually won the case but lost his family in doing so).

Most creative types are not the best business people and need a partner. Paul Allen needed Bill Gates and Wozniak need Jobs. Henry Ford nearly wrecked his company until he listened to those with business sense and stopped making every car black.

OTOH, a discoverer can eschew the patent and make a bundle. Rather than rely on excluding others from entering a certain arena, they—usually with a partner—are the first to take the discovered idea to market, become the best known to buyers, and get a huge head start on any competition. Their position—or location—let’s them dominate. They “corner the market”, make a pile of money, then even more by maintaining the largest market share. All that gain would be due to the discover’s labor and capital, none of it would be due to keeping everyone else out. None would be rent.

At its core, a successful business has a great new idea. But a giant at its core has that plus a stockpile of patents. Giantism can not flourish in a truly free market. It can only come about with the helping hand of the state.

With government-granted patents in hand and another major favor, a favored firm precludes competition, dominates the market, and achieves near monopoly status.

* Ford for a while was untouchable thanks to patents and the tax-paid paving of dirt roads for the newly invented cars;

* Johnson & Johnson is still the biggest pharmaceutical due to patents and limited liability (drugs do harm, too);

* More recently, giants Amazon, Apple, Facebook, and Google benefited from patents and government-funded research.

Government assistance—that’s where super wealthy families come from and what turns IT multi-millionaires into IT multi-billionaires.

While patents and copyrights are justified as ways to encourage creativity, they do just the opposite. Big companies like IBM get literally thousands of patents each year, and little companies called “trolls” get bunches of patents, too. The bigs and not-so-bigs do this not to use the aspect of nature that they’ve staked out but so that you can’t. They’re being a dog in the manger, putting a roadblock in the path of progress.

Ironically, these tech giants may be on their way to utility status, or even there already, and become subject to regulation. Society may legitimately wonder, with this right to exclude, does any responsibility or duty come with it? Like, you may own it, but for excluding every other person from that part of nature, do you owe them compensation for never letting them go there?  Do humans have an equal right to all parts of nature?

Whatever the answers, by posting a “No Trespassing” sign somewhere on the realm of logical solutions, those corporations gain some profit by excluding others. That portion, not the profit earned by applying their labor and capital, but the part due to excluding everyone from exploring aspects of nature, that value is rent.

Like a troll under the bridge, a few of us make money by letting others use our land or idea. As do land titles for absentee landlords—the granddaddy of all privileges—the best patents and copyrights allow the holders to “grow rich in their sleep”. That’s rent, too.

And since government does not charge full market value for its patents and copyrights, the amount that the government does not charge is also rent.

Fees

For granting a patent to an unsellable invention, government charges the same amount as for a patent protecting a hot new app. For granting a title to a quarter acre in Death Valley, government charges the same amount as for a title to a corner lot in midtown Manhattan. In cases of the app and Manhattan, the gulf between filing fee and remuneration yawns like the Grand Canyon. For next to nothing, holders of patents and deeds get to exclude everyone, for a long period of time, and win this without having to compensate society.

If it were a business that issued patents, how much would they charge? They’d not charge everyone the same, but as much as the patent were worth. Pressured by such logic, the government did increase its application fees recently, but not much.

Would inventors still invent if they had to pay full value for a patent? Would writers still write? Of course. People with ideas love to see their ideas in the world. That’s what drives them, not a piece of paper, not a monopoly.

Some creative types even forgo patents and profits. Look at Linux and the rest of Freeware in our current economy of code. Like Jonas Salk (and later Ralph Nader) said, how can you patent the sun?

In the mid 1950s, when polio was crippling kids (earlier President FDR), Jonas Salk and Albert Sabin developed an effective vaccine at nearly the same time. Both chose to not patent their vaccines worth millions, maybe billions. BTW, outside the US, Sabin is more famous for eradicating polio than Salk. And both built on the work of the unheralded Hilary Koprowski.

Rather than hinder progress, a patent fee in line with actual market value would spur inventors and investors to form partnerships. Same with filmmakers and distributors. Nobody would sit on a good idea. Just the opposite of now when an owner of a prime site can let it lie fallow, waiting to cash in later.

Cheaper than patents for discoveries are copyrights for creations—they’re free. Because creations such as stories (some say there are only three … or six … or nine basic plots) can be retold endlessly, even if copyrighted, society loses nothing. Often a creator does not want a copyright. When you hear a new joke, you have no idea who first told it. And why should a jokester not freely contribute to society?

P&C Command Dollars

In our legalistic world, some patents and copyrights do accumulate fortunes—for someone.

It’s standard practice for the government to let Google, Microsoft, Yahoo, and many other tech companies use copyrighted material without a license from the copyright holder. In 2007, the Computer and Communications Industry Association (which includes the tech giants) figured this legal evasion accounted for much of the growth of the previous decade and generated more than $4.5 trillion in annual revenue. How much of that would tech companies be willing to pay as rent? A third? $1.5 trillion?

McKinsey & Company, which gets coverage in the Wall Street Journal (e.g., Jan 10, 2007) for tracking financial assets worldwide (totaling $140 trillion in 2005), estimates that as much as 80% of stock price is accounted for by patents and copyrights. The US stock market in 2018 is $30 trillion, so IP is $24 t. Converting from price to rent puts rent at $3t.

Kevin A. Hassett and Robert J. Shapiro—who do estimates for a living—calculated a total for intellectual capital (patents, copyrights, databases, and general business methods). In 2011 it was as high as $9.2 trillion. Since that figure approaches the then GDP, those guys must have meant price, not annual value. Rent would’ve been $.92t.

In 2013, statisticians put patents at over $5.8 trillion, almost half of the then GDP—that may be a bit over the top. How much of that would be rent? About $1.5 t.

The US Patent Office estimates how much IP—including IT workers and sales and the leverage of exclusion—contributes to the economy. In 2016, they figured over $6 trillion. How much of that is rent—profit due just to exclusion—is hard to say but $2 t is reasonable.

Add that $2 trillion to the $6t we reached by adding eco-losses and utility franchises to land and resources; the new total reaches $8 trillion. That’s equivalent to the drop in global stock prices in 2016 January, to what’d it take to wipe out the US federal deficit, and to how much builders worldwide spend in one year on putting locations to better use.

Eight trillion approaches half of total national income. That’s bigger than either the returns to labor (mostly wages) or to capital (to lenders and investors). (With land, labor and capital are the other two factors in production.) That means the value of our output is due less to anyone’s input—labor or capital—and more to nature and privilege. In other words, you spend more for what nobody made—directly and indirectly—than you pay others for their efforts.

If $8t sounds unbelievable, it’s going to get worse. We’ve reached this height without yet figuring in two more major sources of rents: finance and taxation. Because rent dwarfs earning by effort, and is money for nothing, it attracts speculators. So we go where the money is, as Willy Sutton said—those too big to fail. Me burning up my adding machine blazes a new trail.

This article is Part 24 of a series highlighting the forthcoming book, “Bounty Hunter: a gadfly’s quest to know the worth of Earth,” by Jeffery J. Smith. To date, the experts have not risen to meet the challenge. Indeed, some have even stood in the way. Yet the payoff for knowing this datum is huge.

Find Out More.
Inside information on economics, society, nature, and technology.
Jeffery J. Smith
Activist

JEFFERY J. SMITH published The Geonomist, which won a California GreenLight Award, has appeared in both the popular press (e.g.,TruthOut) and academic journals (e.g., USC's “Planning and Markets”), been interviewed on radio and TV, lobbied officials, testified before the Russian Duma, conducted research (e.g., for Portland's mass transit agency), and recruited activists and academics to Progress.org. A member of the International Society for Ecological Economics and of Mensa, he lives in Mexico. Jeffery formerly was Chief Editor at Progress.org.